This article investigates the issue of commitment by a durable goods monopolist. Two models of the interaction between durability, recycling, and market power are compared. The two differ according to the ability of the seller to credibly commit to a given sales strategy. This article takes the standard durable goods monopoly model, extends it to allow for depreciation, and compares the monopoly markup with Swan's predicted markup for a recycled good. The difference between the two models is shown to reduce to a single parameter in the markup equation.Peer Reviewedhttp://deepblue.lib.umich.edu/bitstream/2027.42/25958/1/0000024.pd
This article considers a durable goods monopolist's choice of price and durability in a setting wher...
Durable goods are more likely to impose binding financial constraint than the perishable goods becau...
This paper reconsiders the proposition put forward by many economists that monopolies would produce ...
This article investigates the issue of commitment by a durable goods monopolist. Two models of the i...
In the presence of moral hazard, the optimal contract for a durable-goods monopolist is a lease with...
In the presence of moral hazard, the optimal contract for a durable-goods monopolist is a lease with...
In the presence of moral hazard, the optimal contract for a durable-goods monopolist is a lease with...
This paper derives and evaluates the decisions of a durable good monopolist in a context where deman...
In his classical model for a durable goods monopoly, Ronald Coase conjectured that a monopoly will...
The "Swan Independence Result" states that a monopolist producer of durable goods will set product d...
We construct a dynamic game to model a monopoly of finitely durable goods. The solution concept is M...
This study analyzes a vertically differentiated market for an imperfectly durable good served by a m...
This study analyzes a vertically differentiated market for an imperfectly durable good served by a m...
Since many publicly owned firms manufacture a durable product we examine a simple two-period, consta...
In a context where demand for the services of a durable good changes over time, and this change may ...
This article considers a durable goods monopolist's choice of price and durability in a setting wher...
Durable goods are more likely to impose binding financial constraint than the perishable goods becau...
This paper reconsiders the proposition put forward by many economists that monopolies would produce ...
This article investigates the issue of commitment by a durable goods monopolist. Two models of the i...
In the presence of moral hazard, the optimal contract for a durable-goods monopolist is a lease with...
In the presence of moral hazard, the optimal contract for a durable-goods monopolist is a lease with...
In the presence of moral hazard, the optimal contract for a durable-goods monopolist is a lease with...
This paper derives and evaluates the decisions of a durable good monopolist in a context where deman...
In his classical model for a durable goods monopoly, Ronald Coase conjectured that a monopoly will...
The "Swan Independence Result" states that a monopolist producer of durable goods will set product d...
We construct a dynamic game to model a monopoly of finitely durable goods. The solution concept is M...
This study analyzes a vertically differentiated market for an imperfectly durable good served by a m...
This study analyzes a vertically differentiated market for an imperfectly durable good served by a m...
Since many publicly owned firms manufacture a durable product we examine a simple two-period, consta...
In a context where demand for the services of a durable good changes over time, and this change may ...
This article considers a durable goods monopolist's choice of price and durability in a setting wher...
Durable goods are more likely to impose binding financial constraint than the perishable goods becau...
This paper reconsiders the proposition put forward by many economists that monopolies would produce ...