Estimates of the effect of education on GDP (the social return) have been hard to reconcile with micro evidence on the private return to schooling. We present a simple explanation combining two ideas: imperfect substitution and endogenous skill-biased technological progress and use cross-country panel data on inequality and GDP to test these ideas. A one-year increase in the level of education reduces the private return by 2 percentage points, consistent with Katz-Murphy's (1992) elasticity of substitution. We find no evidence for reversal of this initial effect as in Acemoglu (2002). In the short run, the social return equals the private return
This paper examines the extent to which patterns of human capital convergence can account for observ...
In the mid 19th century, Horace Mann insisted that a broad provision of public schooling should take...
In this paper we focus on education as a private decision to invest in 'human capital' and the estim...
Estimates of the effect of education on GDP (the social return) have been hard to reconcile with mic...
Estimates of the effect of education on GDP (the social return to education) have been hard to recon...
Estimates of the e¤ect of education on GDP (the social return to education)have been hard to reconci...
In many OECD countries income inequality has risen, but surprisingly redistribution has as well. The...
This paper investigates the relationship between the level and the distribution of education and eco...
We investigate why the economics literature often finds a negative relationship between increased s...
A surprising cross-country stylized fact is that higher public spending on education tends to lower ...
In this paper education simultaneously affects growth and income inequality. More education does not...
This paper explains why different studies present widely-varying estimates of the effect of increase...
In a seminal article, Hanushek and Woessmann explained economic growth as a function of the quality ...
In this paper we focus on education as a private decision to invest in ‘human capital’ and the estim...
Empirical studies assume that the macro Mincer return on schooling is con- stant across countries. U...
This paper examines the extent to which patterns of human capital convergence can account for observ...
In the mid 19th century, Horace Mann insisted that a broad provision of public schooling should take...
In this paper we focus on education as a private decision to invest in 'human capital' and the estim...
Estimates of the effect of education on GDP (the social return) have been hard to reconcile with mic...
Estimates of the effect of education on GDP (the social return to education) have been hard to recon...
Estimates of the e¤ect of education on GDP (the social return to education)have been hard to reconci...
In many OECD countries income inequality has risen, but surprisingly redistribution has as well. The...
This paper investigates the relationship between the level and the distribution of education and eco...
We investigate why the economics literature often finds a negative relationship between increased s...
A surprising cross-country stylized fact is that higher public spending on education tends to lower ...
In this paper education simultaneously affects growth and income inequality. More education does not...
This paper explains why different studies present widely-varying estimates of the effect of increase...
In a seminal article, Hanushek and Woessmann explained economic growth as a function of the quality ...
In this paper we focus on education as a private decision to invest in ‘human capital’ and the estim...
Empirical studies assume that the macro Mincer return on schooling is con- stant across countries. U...
This paper examines the extent to which patterns of human capital convergence can account for observ...
In the mid 19th century, Horace Mann insisted that a broad provision of public schooling should take...
In this paper we focus on education as a private decision to invest in 'human capital' and the estim...