The No Show Paradox (there is a voter who would rather not vote) is known to affect every Condorcet voting function. This paper analyses a strong version of this paradox (there is a voter whose favorite candidate loses the election if she votes honestly, but gets elected if she abstains) in the context of Condorcet voting correspondences. All Condorcet correspondences satisfying some weak domination properties are shown to be affected by this strong form of the paradox. On the other hand, with the exception of the Simpson-Cramer Minmax, all the Condorcet correspondences that (to the best of our knowledge) are proposed in the literature suffer this paradox.
We provide intuitive, formal, and computational evidence that in a large society Condorcet's paradox...
Among all existing paradoxes of voting, the one pointed out by Condorcet has managed to become known...
This paper attacks a problem like the one addressed in an earlier work (Potthoff, 2013) but is more...
The No Show Paradox (there is a voter who would rather not vote) is known to affect every Condorcet ...
We consider two no-show paradoxes, in which a voter obtains a preferable outcome by abstaining from ...
We consider voting correspondences that are, besidesCondorcet Consistent, immune against the two str...
We consider two no-show paradoxes, in which a voter obtains a preferable outcome by abstaining from ...
In elections with variable (and potentially large) electorates, Brams and Fishburn's No Show Paradox...
Voting paradoxes have played an important role in the theory of voting. They typically say very litt...
We report in this note some results on the theoretical likelihood of Condorcet's Other Paradox in th...
In this note, we formulate a condition describing the vulnerability of a social choice function to a...
Condorcet’s paradox occurs when there is no alternative that beats every other alternative by majori...
International audienceWe investigate the possibility of designing a voting rule that both meets the ...
More and more results from social choice theory are used to argue about collective decision making i...
AbstractThe observation of a new type of perverse behavior of voting rules—Brams and Fishburn's “no-...
We provide intuitive, formal, and computational evidence that in a large society Condorcet's paradox...
Among all existing paradoxes of voting, the one pointed out by Condorcet has managed to become known...
This paper attacks a problem like the one addressed in an earlier work (Potthoff, 2013) but is more...
The No Show Paradox (there is a voter who would rather not vote) is known to affect every Condorcet ...
We consider two no-show paradoxes, in which a voter obtains a preferable outcome by abstaining from ...
We consider voting correspondences that are, besidesCondorcet Consistent, immune against the two str...
We consider two no-show paradoxes, in which a voter obtains a preferable outcome by abstaining from ...
In elections with variable (and potentially large) electorates, Brams and Fishburn's No Show Paradox...
Voting paradoxes have played an important role in the theory of voting. They typically say very litt...
We report in this note some results on the theoretical likelihood of Condorcet's Other Paradox in th...
In this note, we formulate a condition describing the vulnerability of a social choice function to a...
Condorcet’s paradox occurs when there is no alternative that beats every other alternative by majori...
International audienceWe investigate the possibility of designing a voting rule that both meets the ...
More and more results from social choice theory are used to argue about collective decision making i...
AbstractThe observation of a new type of perverse behavior of voting rules—Brams and Fishburn's “no-...
We provide intuitive, formal, and computational evidence that in a large society Condorcet's paradox...
Among all existing paradoxes of voting, the one pointed out by Condorcet has managed to become known...
This paper attacks a problem like the one addressed in an earlier work (Potthoff, 2013) but is more...