The rate of return to investment in thoroughbred racehorses is widely believed to be negative on average. In a world of fully informed market participants, this implies that ownership of a racehorse is motivated in part by nonfinancial attributes, perhaps a taste for sport. This article presents simple models of the utility derived from sporting competition. The models differ in their implications for the rate of return to racehorse ownership and its variation with the level of talent. Evidence from thoroughbred auctions and racing earnings are used to test between the models.Sports
This empirical and theoretical investigation into betting markets provides more evidence on the issu...
Chezum and Wimmer (2000) show the impact of asymmetric information in the American thoroughbred indu...
This paper looks for evidence of weak form inefficiency in the British racetrack betting market, in ...
Most analyses of the earnings of thoroughbred racehorses indicate that the average return to ownersh...
Horse racing is a popular sport in many countries for racing on the flat, over obstacles, and with c...
A horse’s lifespan ranges from 20 to 30 years while a Thoroughbred racehorse’s career averages just ...
Thoroughbred racehorses are commonly characterized as unprofitable investments. Previous studies, g...
This paper reviews the literature addressing the degree to which abnormal returns can be earned in h...
The thoroughbred horseracing industry is mired in a situation where many of the owners of the typica...
Horse racing is a popular sport in many countries for racing on the flat, over obstacles, and with c...
This study estimates the price determinants of show quality quarter horses sold at auction. Several ...
This study estimates the price determinants of show quality quarter horses sold at auction. Several ...
Thoroughbred broodmares are the foundation of a successful racing operation. This study estimated th...
Both quantity of horses and quality stimulate demand for horse race gambling. This paper addresses...
Thoroughbred incentive programs are subsidy policies designed to promote regional race horse breedin...
This empirical and theoretical investigation into betting markets provides more evidence on the issu...
Chezum and Wimmer (2000) show the impact of asymmetric information in the American thoroughbred indu...
This paper looks for evidence of weak form inefficiency in the British racetrack betting market, in ...
Most analyses of the earnings of thoroughbred racehorses indicate that the average return to ownersh...
Horse racing is a popular sport in many countries for racing on the flat, over obstacles, and with c...
A horse’s lifespan ranges from 20 to 30 years while a Thoroughbred racehorse’s career averages just ...
Thoroughbred racehorses are commonly characterized as unprofitable investments. Previous studies, g...
This paper reviews the literature addressing the degree to which abnormal returns can be earned in h...
The thoroughbred horseracing industry is mired in a situation where many of the owners of the typica...
Horse racing is a popular sport in many countries for racing on the flat, over obstacles, and with c...
This study estimates the price determinants of show quality quarter horses sold at auction. Several ...
This study estimates the price determinants of show quality quarter horses sold at auction. Several ...
Thoroughbred broodmares are the foundation of a successful racing operation. This study estimated th...
Both quantity of horses and quality stimulate demand for horse race gambling. This paper addresses...
Thoroughbred incentive programs are subsidy policies designed to promote regional race horse breedin...
This empirical and theoretical investigation into betting markets provides more evidence on the issu...
Chezum and Wimmer (2000) show the impact of asymmetric information in the American thoroughbred indu...
This paper looks for evidence of weak form inefficiency in the British racetrack betting market, in ...